Loading...

Archive

    20 July 2022, Volume 43 Issue 7 Previous Issue    Next Issue

    For Selected: Toggle Thumbnails
    Research on evolution of the smart city policy system in China
    Li Xia, Chen Qi, Jia Hongman
    2022, 43(7): 1-10. 
    Abstract ( 412 )  
        Smart city is the intelligent performance of innovative applications for information technology embedded in social service and management. Smart city pilot projects have gradually been included in 89% of provincial and sub-provincial cities whereas repetitive or conflicting construction has shown the potential negative impact on urban resource due to policy ambiguity, although the government has taken a series of measures to promote the smart construction process. Therefore, this paper establishes an analysis framework of policy instruments based on resource utility - technical structure - application field, text content analysis, social network analysis and multidimensional scale analysis are used to analyze the evolution of smart city policies, policy network relations, co-occurrence keywords from year 2011 to 2021. Meanwhile, explores the structural evolution process of supply-oriented, environment-oriented and demand-oriented policy instruments in IoT sensing platform policies, cloud computing industrial policies and smart application service policies in smart city. The main valid data set related to smart city policy document issued by the central state ministries and functional departments of local government are collected, and then analyzed through text content unit encoding, from which the following conclusions can be inferred.
        The first conclusion shows that smart city policy has experienced three evolutionary stages involving in perceptive infrastructure and top-level design stage, cultivation and innovation-driven stage of smart industry, and heterogeneous development of smart application field. In the first stage, the technical concept and architecture system of the Internet of Things are put forward; in the second stage, intensive promulgation and rapid development of core supporting technology are reflected, involving big data, artificial intelligence and other strategic emerging industry; and in the third stage, the application integration of smart government, smart medical and smart transportation are exhibited, gradually expanding to various application systems such as smart environment and security.
       The second one reveals that many independent network groups have developed in smart city policy network, early policies mostly focused on top-level construction of infrastructure in relevant to Internet of Things and gradually transferred to implementation in heterogeneous domain in terms of programmatic policy document.
       The third one points out the thematic evolution of smart city policy at different evolutionary stages. Policy theme at the first stage covering policy objectives, foundational technology, organizational security system, and policy theme at the second stage take consideration of synergy of industrial structure optimization and innovation resources, establishment of innovation environment, technology standardization and evaluation. Policy theme at the third stage means data fusion, heterogeneous smart application fields and policy effect.
       The fourth one expounds the structurally unbalanced in smart city policies, and compared with the supply-oriented policy instruments that were used steadily in the initial stage of evolution, environment-oriented policy instruments are steadily increasing, while demand-oriented policy instruments are dynamically matched. In comparison with the cloud computing support industry layer dominated by supply-oriented policy instruments, IoT platform policies tend to combine utility of supply-oriented and environment-oriented. smart application policies are adaptive coupled with environment-oriented policy instruments and further developed from government-oriented pattern to market-oriented collaboration, with public service, scientific and technological information support are frequently employed. IoT sensing platform policies emphasis on smart infrastructure, while cloud computing industrial policies are influenced by citizen participation mechanism, innovation and entrepreneurship measures with top-level design and regulations. Priorities of smart construction are adaptive to different evolutionary path of smart application fields from early technology architecture, and gradually upgraded to industrial innovation chain system from environment-oriented instruments.
        Finally, this study puts forward some suggestions to improve relevant policies, including optimization of supply-oriented and environment-oriented policy instruments structure for sensing platform, balanced application of environment-oriented and demand-oriented policy tools in supporting smart industries; development of data fusion, data mining and demonstration application of commercial database to foster emerging strategic industrial clusters, structured configuration procurement, collaborative incentives for innovation and entrepreneurship as well to provide strong support for high-quality development of smart city.
    References | Related Articles | Metrics
    The operational efficiency of the regional innovation ecosystem in China: A study based on the perspective of innovation value chain
    2022, 43(7): 11-19. 
    Abstract ( 253 )  
        With today′s society entering the era of a knowledge economy, innovation has become an essential driving force to promote economic development, and it is closely tied to national prosperity and people′s happiness. Innovation ability is the critical competitive force of a country′s comprehensive national strength, which can control economic development, optimize the economic structure, and promote sustainable development. In China, it can be seen that the creation of new knowledge, technologies, and products has always been encouraged. Subsequently, the research on regional innovation has been paid more attention by researchers. As a significant driving force to promote China′s high-quality economic growth, the regional innovation ecosystem′s coordinated and effective operation also guarantees the modernization of China′s system and capacity for governance. In comparison, regional innovation′s framework and operation are rarely explored from systematic ecology in some research. In essence, regional innovation is an ecological problem. The effective operation of regional innovation depends on the cooperation and mutual benefit among various elements. Collaboration and mutual help among different elements play an essential role in the effective operation of regional innovation, which will cause the shortboard effect of improving regional innovation ability due to the lack and lag of any element. As a result, it will influence the optimal allocation of regional innovation resources due to the neglect of this problem, which quickly causes the dilemma of regional innovation.
        Based on the above analyses, this paper starts from the perspective of the innovation value chain. It systematically constructs a regional innovation ecosystem integration framework which includes four innovation elements: policy innovation environment - original innovation research and development - technology innovation application - technology innovation service. On this basis, the Malmquist index method is used to conduct a dynamic empirical evaluation on the operation efficiency of the regional innovation ecosystem in China from the perspective of input and output during 2014-2018, and the sensitivity analysis of the influencing factors of input dimension is also carried out. The results indicate that: (1) From 2014 to 2018, China′s regional innovation ecosystem′s operation efficiency showed stable growth, with an average annual increase of 9.7%. After 2016, the technical efficiency decreased, mainly due to the impact of scale efficiency changes. (2) The operation efficiency of the innovation ecosystem in eastern China is closer to the optimization frontier, followed by the central and western regions. However, the inter-provincial innovation ecosystem′s efficiency varies greatly, mainly caused by the significant difference in technological change index among provinces. The change index of technological progress in each area shows a closer trend to total factor productivity. (3) The various sensitivity of each province region to different resource input exists. Some problems are the redundancy of innovation input resources or poor management of distribution to another degree. 
        To ensure the steady growth of the operation efficiency of China′s regional innovation ecosystem,the following suggestions are put forward: (1) Recognize the gap of innovation strength with other provinces and strengthen the cooperation between regions. (2) Allocate input resources reasonably, enhance the efficiency of resource allocation. (3) Encourage technological progress, and improve the scientific research management system. 
        In terms of the possible contribution of this thesis, it lies in the following aspects: Firstly, based on the perspective of the innovation value chain, this paper proposes an explanatory framework for analyzing the operational framework of the regional innovation ecosystem, which enriches the components and transmission path of regional innovation ecosystem from the theoretical level. Secondly, the Malmquist index method is used to measure efficiency and analyze China′s regional innovation ecosystem′s heterogeneity from 2014 to 2018. Furthermore, we test the sensitivity of input resources from the perspective of resource allocation, which will improve the collaborative operation efficiency of China′s regional innovation ecosystem and optimize the allocation of regional innovation resources.
    References | Related Articles | Metrics
    A study of the "point to area" effect in pilot project construction of innovative cities
    Yan Yanyang, Wang Juan, Lu Yanjin
    2022, 43(7): 20-28. 
    Abstract ( 157 )  
        Construction of pilot projects is a policy making process with Chinese characteristics. From the perspective of innovative-city construction, this paper examines whether there is "point to area" effect in the process of implementing pilot projects and further analyzes its mechanism. Innovative-city construction is an important measure to build innovative country and realize the innovation-driven development strategy. In 2008, Shenzhen was approved as the first national innovative-city pilot area. Then in 2010, the Ministry of Science and Technology issued "Notice on Promoting the National Innovative-city Pilot Work", identifying Dalian, Qingdao and other 16 cities as the national innovative-city pilot areas. By 2019, the number of national innovative-city pilot area reached 78. In terms of implementation process, this is a typical Chinese experience of "pilot-extended-demonstration". However, few empirical studies focused on the effect of innovative-city construction, especially the demonstration effect of innovative-city construction.  
        In China, pilot policies usually have two political missions. On the one hand, pilot project construction is a summary of experience. In the policy formulation process, local governments of pilot cities are encouraged to try various solutions to problems based on local characteristics, and feedback the experience to the central government. On the other hand, pilot project construction is supposed to produce a demonstration effect. The typical successful experience of the pilot area is promoted through media reports, experience exchange meetings, visits and learning activities, so that other regions imitate them, thereby producing the effect of "point to area".
        However, pilot cities usually receive policy incentives from the central and other levels of government, they may also trigger the accumulation of resources from other regions, especially neighboring cities. As a result, pilot cities will have a negative impact on the innovation of neighboring cities, presenting the so-called "siphon effect". Based on this, this research attempts to answer the following questions: Does the pilot city have an impact on the innovation of neighboring cities? Is this effect a demonstration effect? Is it continuous? Is it heterogeneity with urban characteristics? What are the paths?  
        Using the panel data of 266 cities at or above prefecture-level from 2003 to 2016, we evaluate the effect produced by the innovative-city construction pilot project. In order to control possible problems of sample self-selection, we use the propensity score matching method (PSM) to process the samples. Then, a double difference model (DID) is employed to evaluate the "pilot effect" and its dynamic evolution, and a triple difference model (DDD) is constructed to test heterogeneity. Further study examines the policy diffusion path and factor flow path from the perspective of peer effect and factor agglomeration. 
        The findings are as follows: (1) Innovative-city construction has a demonstration effect, which significantly improves the innovation level of neighboring cities. The effect is the largest in the east and the smallest in the west. Furthermore, the effect is persistent and reaches a peak in the third year after the pilot. (2) The demonstration effect is heterogeneous with urban characteristics, it is more significant among cities that are not geographically connected to the pilot cities, and cities at sub-provincial level or above. (3) Innovative-city construction acts on neighboring cities through the neighborhood effect of government innovation policy and promoting the agglomeration of innovation elements in neighboring cities.  
      The policy implications of this study include: (1) The government should continue to expand the scale of innovative-city construction and promote the orderly diffusion of innovative city. In the process of layout of innovative cities, the positive externality of innovative city construction should be considered. The comprehensive strategic layout of innovative cities should be carried out from multiple angles such as geographical location and city level. (2) In order to achieve a more positive demonstration effect, the policy diffusion path should be fully utilized. It is necessary to sum up the experience and achievement of innovative city construction in time. At the same time, advanced experience should be promoted through a variety of channels to expand the influence. (3) Regional interaction should be strengthened and collaborative innovation should be encouraged. The interconnection of innovation elements should be fully considered when a series of supporting measures are taken to construct innovative cities. Regional cooperation networks should be actively formed to achieve a win-win result.
    References | Related Articles | Metrics
    Research on performance measurement and optimization of cross-regional collaborative innovation system
    Wu Weihong, Feng Xingkui, Zhang Aimei, Tang Fangcheng
    2022, 43(7): 29-36. 
    Abstract ( 134 )  
        The existing research seldom examines collaborative innovation from a cross-regional perspective, and in the process of measuring collaborative innovation performance, it is often overlooked that the collaborative connection of all parties involved, resulting in a certain deviation between the measured collaborative innovation performance and the actual situation, which is difficult to truly reflect the current situation and existing problems of the cross-regional collaborative innovation performance. Cross-regional collaborative innovation can realize the free flow of innovation elements among innovation subjects in different regions and produce a "1+1>2" system synergy effect. And cross-regional collaborative innovation can also provide endogenous motivation for regional coordinated development and plays an important driving role in the implementation of regional coordinated development strategy. Therefore, it is necessary to accurately measure the performance of cross-regional collaborative innovation and deeply explore the constraints of performance improvement.
        Before measuring the cross-regional collaborative innovation performance, it is necessary to clarify the connotation of collaborative innovation performance. And previous studies have studied the collaborative innovation performance of innovation subjects such as industries, universities and research institutes from the dimensions of collaborative input and collaborative output. But in their process of researching, the independent innovation inputs and innovation outputs of the subjects were used to represent the collaborative inputs and the collaborative outputs between the subjects. That is, the collaborative innovation performance is understood as the sum of the respective innovation performance of the innovation subjects participating in the collaboration. However, the essence of collaborative innovation is the organic integration of innovation elements and the free flow of innovation elements among all the parties in the synergy. But the organic integration of innovation elements is not a simple summary of innovation resources of all parties, but through the integration of complementary resources, the complementary advantages of all parties can be realized, resulting in "1+1>2" synergy effect. The cross-border flow of innovation elements establishes synergy link between the parties. However, simply taking the innovation input and output of each party as the collaborative input and output of each other not only cuts off the synergistic connection between the parties, but also hardly reflects the synergy effect produced by the parties′ collaborative innovation. Collaborative innovation across regions is the organic integration and dynamic flow of innovative elements such as capital and manpower across regional boundaries and organizational boundaries among innovative entities in different regions, which results in a systematic superposition of non-linear effect and ultimately promotes regional collaborative development.  Therefore, this study believes that the performance of cross-regional collaborative innovation is the performance of multi-innovation subjects in different regions cooperating with each other to jointly carry out scientific and technological innovation activities. And the key to accurately measure the performance of cross-regional collaborative innovation lies in the reasonable measurement of inter-regional collaborative inputs and collaborative outputs.
        On the basis of clarifying the connotation of cross-regional collaborative innovation performance, this study built a composite system of cross-regional collaborative innovation. It measured the collaborative input and output of different regions to characterize the synergistic relationship between different regional innovation subjects, and then the DEA-Tobit two-stage model was used to measure the cross-regional collaborative innovation performance in the Yangtze River Delta region and Beijing-Tianjin-Hebei region from 2013 to 2016. Combined with the new economic geography, it analyzed the measurement results of cross-regional collaborative innovation performance, and the key influencing factors of cross-regional collaborative innovation performance were further identified and verified.
        The research results found that: (1) The level of collaborative innovation performance among various regions within the Yangtze River Delta is distributed in a ladder-like and diversified manner. Among them, the level of collaborative innovation performance of Zhejiang-Anhui, Jiangsu-Zhejiang belong to the first echelon, Shanghai-Anhui, Jiangsu-Zhejiang belong to the second echelon, and Shanghai-Zhejiang and Shanghai-Jiangsu belong to the third echelon. The level of collaborative innovation performances of Jiangsu- Anhui, Zhejiang- Anhui and Shanghai- Anhui are higher than that between Jiangsu-Zhejiang, Zhejiang-Shanghai and Jiangsu-Shanghai, and shows a certain difference due to their geographical proximity. (2) The level of collaborative innovation performance among regions within Beijing, Tianjin and Hebei is extremely distributed. The collaborative innovation performances of Beijing-Tianjin and Beijing-Hebei all have reached a very high level, while the level of collaborative innovation performance of Tianjin-Hebei is far lower than that of Beijing-Tianjin and Beijing-Hebei due to the limitation of the insufficient scale of collaborative innovation, low technical efficiency and the inhibitory effect of similar resources advantages. (3) The overall collaborative innovation performance level in Yangtze River Delta is higher than that in Beijing, Tianjin and Hebei. Regardless of overall efficiency or technical efficiency and scale efficiency, there is a large gap between the Beijing-Tianjin-Hebei region and the Yangtze River Delta region. (4) The degree of inter-regional synergy has a significant positive impact on the performance of cross-regional collaborative innovation. Geographical proximity can also promote the performance of cross-regional collaborative innovation to a certain extent, while the gap of inter-regional economic development has a weak impact on the performance of cross-regional collaborative innovation.
       Finally, two optimization suggestions for improving performance are put forward:(1) For the Yangtze River Delta region, it is necessary to clarify the core position of each region′s development, promote the rational transfer of innovative resources, and continuously improve the level of regional coordinated development. Jiangsu, Zhejiang and Shanghai should reasonably transfer the innovative resources that are excessively concentrated according to the current situation of regional economic and social development. Anhui should make reasonable use of its "value depression" and its geographical proximity advantages to sequentially undertake the innovative resource elements overflowing from Jiangsu, Zhejiang and Shanghai. (2) For the Beijing-Tianjin-Hebei region, while giving full play to the leading role of Beijing′s "core" in promoting the "two wings" of Tianjin and Hebei, attention should also be paid to strengthening the collaborative innovation links between the "two wings" and constantly seeking the joint points of Tianjin and Hebei′s collaborative innovation, such as setting up a collaborative innovation center according to the related industries of the two places, so as to promote the promotion of synergy between Tianjin and Hebei.
    Related Articles | Metrics
    Can industrial-urban integration promote regional innovation?——The empirical evidence from 285 prefecture-level cities in China
    Liu Shiyuan, Xiang Hailing, Wu Fei
    2022, 43(7): 37-44. 
    Abstract ( 201 )  
       The report of the 19th National Congress of the Communist Party of China pointed out that innovation is the primary driving force for development and a strategic support for building a modern economic system. How to promote regional innovation in China? As a basic carrier of regional development, cities are closely related to regional economic development and even technological innovation, and even become important drivers of regional innovation. But does this indicate that current urban development can effectively promote regional innovation? Unfortunately, the answer to this question is not necessarily positive. In recent years, with the rapid advancement of urbanization, significant progress has been made in urban construction, and contradictions cannot be ignored. The construction of local government cities relies too much on the development of a "single production park economy", which has an almost instinctive impulse to the construction of infrastructure and so on, not much on how to achieve "harmonious development" between cities and industries, which will inevitably ignore the concern of industry and population development, thus falling into the misunderstanding of "separation of production and city".
       In this background, the Chinese government has gradually realized the problem of urban construction, and has thus proposed the strategic goal of "industrial-urban integration". In 2014, the Central Committee of the Communist Party of China and the State Council issued the National New Urbanization Plan (2014-2020), which adopted "industrial-urban integration" as China′s leading thought on the development of new urbanization. The idea is to take the city as a carrier, carry industrial space and develop industrial economy, and take industry as a guarantee to promote urban renewal and improve service facilities, so as to achieve a high-quality development model that is dependent on and promotes each other in terms of population, industry and city. It can be said that the "industrial-urban integration" policy has become an important focus of urban construction and has played an important role in promoting the healthy and sustainable development of cities. After several years of practice, it has also reached the point of time to test its innovation-driven performance. However, there is very little discussion about "industrial-urban integration" in academic circles at present, mainly focusing on the analysis of the concept of "industrial-urban integration" and index measurement. In addition, there are a few literatures that discuss the formation mechanism of "industrial-urban integration" through constructing models and empirical evidences, while few discussions on the economic (innovative) effects of "industrial-urban integration".
        Then, does the "industry-city integration" strategy have a positive macroeconomic effect? The existing literature rarely addresses this issue. Based on the perspective of innovation, this paper links "production-city integration-regional innovation" for the first time, and empirically analyzes the impact of production-city integration on regional innovation. Specifically, this paper manually collected panel data of 285 prefecture-level cities in China from 2003 to 2016, used the number of patents granted at the city level as a measure of regional innovation, and used the principle of coupling and coordination in physics to calculate the degree of integration between industries and cities. Empirical analysis found that the improvement of the integration of production and city can significantly promote the development of regional innovation. 
        Furthermore, we have explored the two parts of "driving mechanism" and "conduction mechanism". Firstly, we use the ratio of urban land "recruitment and auction" price to the negotiated transfer price to indicate the path of "pre-production and then city". The ratio of the area of land sold by auction to the area of land transferred by agreement represents the path of "first city and then production". The higher the value of this indicator, the deeper the city "first city and then production". We found that, the path of "produce first and then produce cities" is guided by industrial development, which can easily lead to the misconfiguration of industrial development and the comparative advantages of urban resources, hinder the process of industrial transformation and upgrading, which is not conducive to the improvement of regional innovation quality. In comparison, the "first city and later production" path can better attract investment and attract talents to promote urban development. Relatively speaking, this path pays more attention to the "composite functions" of the city, and more emphasis on the coordination between the development of the city and the industry, which is conducive to promoting the integration of production and city, thereby improving the level of regional innovation. Finally, this paper uses the mediation effect model to test the intermediate mechanism and found that "industry-city integration" can affect the regional innovation level from the three paths of "human-oriented", "industrial change" and "function matching". It can improve the accumulation of urban human capital, promote industrial upgrading, and improve the urban environment, thereby playing a role in increasing the level of regional innovation.
       This paper suggests that we should unswervingly promote the integration of production and city, and avoid excessive emphasis on the development of one of the "production" or "city". Government intervention should be moderately reduced, the decisive role of the market in resource allocation should be brought into full play, and the loss of production efficiency caused by the government′s over-planning of "production" and "city" should be avoided. Urban planning should fully consider its own comparative advantages. The actual industry introduction and upgrading strategy promotes the integration of production and urban development, thereby promoting the improvement of regional innovation. In addition, the idea of promoting urbanization should be changed from "introducing phoenixes and building nests" to "building nests and attracting phoenixes", and develop targeted regional innovation promotion strategies based on the characteristics of the city. From the perspective of the urbanization construction path, the mode of "building nests and attracting phoenixes" (that is, "first in the city and then in production") that optimizes the location conditions can better bring out the innovative effects of the integration of production and city. Relatively speaking, the development mode of "produce first and then the city" is more likely to cause the dislocation of industrial development and the comparative advantage of the city.
    Related Articles | Metrics
    Measurement of technological involution: A study of methods and an analysis of cases
    Zhang Mier, Ren Tengfei, Liu Ximei
    2022, 43(7): 45-52. 
    Abstract ( 257 )  
        The global technology development is facing stagflation in recent years. On the one hand, the number of patents and theses increases rapidly. On the other hand, there is a lack of original innovations and technology development tends to partial improvement and incremental innovation. This is essentially caused by the involution in technology field. Involution is a phenomenon that is limited by the original model. The development tends to be internalization and refinement due to difficulty in expanding system boundary. The research of involution began in agricultural field. Researchers adopted the sociological paradigm and obtained enlightening results. Technological involution is a phenomenon that technology development tends to be partial improvement and incremental innovation under competitive pressure in the context of a long-term lack of technological breakthroughs. It is a challenge to analyze the emerging phenomenon of technological involution. Faced with the spread of technological involution, it is necessary to carry out targeted research to measure technological involution.
        With the technology development falling into involution, the modified innovations emerged and led to the number of patents increasing continuously. It is difficult to analyze the patent time series with the logistic curve model. Patent family is contributor to the rapid growth of patents. Patents include basic patent and patent family. Basic patent is independent of other patents and it represents the substantive progress of technology. Patent family is a collection of patent applications covering the same or similar technical content. The quality of patent family is generally lower than that of basic patent. Patent family represents incremental improvement of original technology, and it is the key to analyze technological involution. Therefore, we construct technological involution index (TII) based on patent family to analyze technological involution in target field. The numerator is the sum of simple patent family and extended patent family. The denominator is the number of the patent for invention. The higher the TII is, the higher the degree of technological involution is. It indicates that the technology development tends to be partial improvement and incremental innovation, and patent family dominates the growth of patent.
           We select chemical battery technology as a sample and utilize the TII to analyze the long-term process of the technological involution. Chemical battery technology is an important field, which is widely applied in electric vehicles, energy storage, mobile devices, etc. Lithium battery became the mainstream of chemical battery after the rechargeable battery technology appeared in 1976. However, there is lack of principle breakthrough in lithium battery technology since its commercial application in 1991. The chemical battery technology developed slowly in recent decades, while the number of patents continues increasing. We obtain patent time series in chemical battery field from 1980 to 2018. The TII shows that the technological involution presents an increasing trend in the field. We utilize K-means cluster method to analyze the evolution stage and reveal the stage features. The results show that technological involution goes through a long-term process of dynamic evolution, including low involution stage, acceleration involution stage and high involution stage. The low involution stage lasted from 1980 to 2000. The TII gradually increased to 0.825 in the acceleration involution stage from 2000 to 2011. The high involution stage started from 2012, the TII continued increasing and gradually reached its peak. Patent family accounted for 86.8% while basic patent accounted for 13.2% of the whole patents in 2018. In the high involution stage, technology development tended to be partial improvement around basic patents. The energy density of chemical battery improved slowly, and it is necessary to seek for technological breakthroughs.
         Faced with the challenge of technological involution, it is feasible to utilize the TII to monitor the trend of technological innovation. The stagnation of technical principle is the inducement of technological involution. We should break the path dependence of incremental innovation in the field in high involution and seek for technological breakthroughs to achieve the target of breaking involution. Patents are widely employed as basis for science and technology evaluation. However, the proportion of patent family significantly exceeds that of basic patents in the field in high involution. Patent family is derivative of basic patent and the quality is lower than basic patent. Therefore, we should prevent the interference of excessive growth of patent family on science and technology evaluation, and reduce the weight of patent family when evaluating technology in high involution.
    References | Related Articles | Metrics
    A case study of the construction of "enabling" innovation ecology in science and technology parks
    Li Guoqiang, Hu Wenan, Sun Yuchun
    2022, 43(7): 53-60. 
    Abstract ( 139 )  
        Innovation ecosystem and its relation to sustainable economic development are topics of great interest to strategy researchers, think-tanks and government agencies. Hence, innovation ecosystem continues to be one of the most widely studied fields in strategic management research. Likewise, since it was formally put forward by academia, the definition of innovation ecosystem has aroused the interest and concern of the world community. Organization and strategy scholars have recognized that the construction of innovation ecosystem is an indicator of economic growth and enterprise development that has important implications for corporate and regional governance. 
        Based on the perspective of inter-organizational relationship and the commercial ecology, this paper puts forward the fundamental theory of enabling innovation ecosystem, aiming to explain the elements and the triggering mechanism of enabling innovation ecosystem in order to provide theoretical guidance for science and technology parks. The inter-organizational relationship in science and technology parks has changed from property leasing to mutualistic symbiosis. Meanwhile, the relationship between companies and employees has shifted from employment to cooperation. The organizational structure of the enterprise has changed from a hierarchical structure to a self-driving and self-optimizing system. 
       With the present research, this paper contributes to the literature on innovation ecosystem in several ways. First, the study explores the link between enabling and innovation ecosystem based on classical innovation theory, proposing a theoretical framework of enabling innovation ecosystem. Second, we extend research on cross-enterprise differences in innovation strategy and address a vital gap by focusing on how interorganizational structures shape ambidextrous innovation of enterprises. An improved understanding of the relationship among enabling innovation ecosystem, S&T Parks and organizational features does not just contribute to a superior financial performance of profit-oriented organizations in a market system but also enables management to realize the ‘triple win’ situation. Finally, we further extend our research by using a qualitative approach to explore how internal and external features of enterprises combine to shape innovation differences across enterprises. 
       Generalizing theories from qualitative data is a main objective of this study, as a systematic methodology in the social sciences involving the construction of theory through methodic gathering and analysis of data, the value of the grounded theory lines in its ability not only to generate the theory but also to ground that theory in data. Grounded theory equipped with a set of perfect and rigorous analytical criteria to ensure the accuracy and verifiability of the findings. Based on the paradigm of grounded theory, this paper contributes to our understanding of following topics: (a) in macroscopic view, what kinds of organizational structure should formed by organizational entities in science and technology parks, including management organization, enterprises, universities, scientific research institutions, etc.; (b) what relationship should be established between the science and technology parks and the enterprise, what relationship should be established between enterprises and employees, and what relationship should be established between the enterprise and the enterprise in science and technology parks; (c) how to understand the paradoxes in the process of collaborative innovation and how to deal with them properly.
        As a part of the national innovation system, Science and Technology Parks were regarded as an important engine of regional economic development, carrying a lot of innovative elements, such as technology, talents, funds and so on. According to the assumption of enabling innovation ecosystem, the foundation of the organization design in the science and technology parks switch from organizational entities to individuals in organizations. Taking the management practice of Caohejing Hi-Tech Development Zone as a research case, this paper adopts the exploratory embedded case study method to explain the elements, operation rules and evolution process of enabling innovation ecosystem in science and technology parks. 
        In addition, it was found that the form of enabling cooperative innovation ecology in Caohejing High-Tech Development Zone mainly depends on the improvement of the enabling platform. Management philosophy has undergone a new?revolution: the new paradigm of park development based on system view provides strategic guidance for the development of Caohejing Hi-tech Zone. Caohejing has established more extensive contact with the supply chain partners, through the smooth implementation of cooperation plan, the products and services of the partners would be embedded in their own ecology. An online service platform was created for enterprise customization, mainly including property maintenance, parking management, visitor management, business information and other scenarios to achieve closed-loop management. According to the actual needs of enterprises, Caohejing high-tech zone is equipped with fully open office space with complete facilities, which can be used for office and reduces the cost for start-ups. For technology start-ups, the financing paradox is the primary obstacle to their rapid development, traditional financial institutions are unable to provide effective support for such enterprises for the sake of capital security. In order to solve the problems of expensive capital cost for enterprises in the initial stage, Caohejing has set up a new financial model, and implemented credit loans for small and medium-sized science and technology enterprises. Based on the concept of building comprehensive enabling platform, Caohejing public technology platform provides technical research and development, the optimization of process validation, product testing, equipment sharing, information consultation and training of education for small and medium enterprises.
        The study also explores the underlying mechanism of enabling innovation ecology by case analyzing in multi-dimension based on macro-industry level, meso-park level and micro-enterprise level respectively. Depending on differences of concept, the development process of Caohejing high-tech zone could be divided into four stages, the exploration cultivation period (1984-1991), the rapid growth period (1992-2002), the optimization period (2003-2008), the innovation period (2009-present). Through case analysis, the results show that an efficient collaborative innovation ecosystem could be achieved by a) standardized operation and standardized construction of enabling platform; b) attaching importance to empowerment of employees to build a symbiotic organizational structure; c) building smart park system using information technology and implementing service enabling; d) exploring the standardized operation of public technology enabling platform and implementing technology enabling platform; e) exporting brand and management mode actively and expanding the extension of innovative ecology geographically.
    Related Articles | Metrics
    Do suppliers bring more R&D innovation or non-R&D innovation to manufacturers?——A study from the perspective of social capital
    Zhu Mingwei, Li Suicheng
    2022, 43(7): 61-68. 
    Abstract ( 153 )  
       Under the background of open innovation, making use of suppliers′ innovation ability or strengthening the depth of cooperation has become an important means to improve the innovation performance of manufacturing enterprises, but the cooperation with suppliers will not significantly promote the R&D innovation of manufacturing enterprises. Due to the complexity and uncertainty of R&D tasks, the weak absorptive capacity of enterprises and the limited depth of cooperation, the R&D capacity promoted by manufacturing enterprises is limited.
        Although manufacturers′ ability to improve R&D innovation by suppliers is limited, the process technology information, technological transformation plan and market dynamic information acquired in cooperation will improve the non-R&D innovation level of manufacturing enterprises. Non-R&D innovation is different from traditional R&D innovation, it mainly includes technical or non-technical innovation activities such as imitation, improvement and improvement of new products or technologies, organizational learning and user innovation. Non-R&D innovation has gradually attracted the attention of enterprises: On the one hand, compared with R&D innovation, non-R&D innovation has shorter time cycle, lower cost and strong selectivity. On the other hand, the output of non-R&D innovation is relatively high and the profits are relatively fast, while the short-term profits of enterprises are applied to long-term R&D activities, which is more conducive to give full play to the utilization rate of innovation resources, ensure the long-term investment in R&D, and then improve the innovation performance of enterprises. Therefore, an in-depth study on the path mechanism of manufacturing enterprises to promote non-R&D innovation in the context of supply chain provides beneficial ideas for the improvement of innovation capability. Therefore, non-R&D innovation is an important way to improve the innovation performance of manufacturing enterprise, but few studies have proved the structure of non-R&D innovation and the relationship between R&D innovation and non-R&D innovation in the context of supply chain.
       Based on all above, the main contents of this paper are as follows: Firstly, the conceptual model of manufacturer supplier social capital and R&D or non-R&D innovation is constructed, and nine hypotheses are put forward. Specifically, the structural capital, cognitive capital and relational capital of manufacturer-supplier has a positive impact on manufacturer′s R&D and non-R&D innovation. Compared with R&D innovation, the structural capital of manufacturer-supplier has a stronger impact on non-R&D innovation, but the cognitive capital and relational capital of manufacturer-supplier has a stronger impact on R&D innovation than non-R&D innovation.
       Secondly, the measurement scale is designed. A large-scale questionnaire survey was conducted by issuing questionnaires, and 538 questionnaires were collected from 206 enterprises. AMOS21.0 and SPSS24.0 were used to verify the reliability and validity of the scale. (1) All dimensions of manufacturer-supplier social capital positively affect R&D innovation and non-R&D innovation; (2) Compared with R&D innovation, structural capital and cognitive capital has a stronger impact on non-R&D innovation in manufacturing companies; but relational capital of manufacturer-supplier has a stronger impact on R&D innovation than non-R&D innovation; (3) structural capital, cognitive capital and relational capital have an positive impact on each dimension of non-R&D innovation (product or process improvement, imitation innovation, technology introduction and market innovation).
        Finally, based on the empirical results, the research conclusion clarifies the differential impact of different dimensions of manufacturer-supplier social capital on R&D or non-R&D innovation, providing a theoretical explanation for manufacturing enterprises to improve R&D innovation/non-R&D innovation. In addition, there are three aspects of practical significance in this research, to help enterprises better improve innovation ability.
    References | Related Articles | Metrics
    Financial misallocation and enterprise innovation: Research on policy distortion and financial frictions
    Tong Xiaoge, Ran Maosheng, Li Wanli
    2022, 43(7): 69-76. 
    Abstract ( 203 )  
        Innovation has become a "new engine" to promote China′s economic growth and a key factor in the success or failure of economic restructuring. How to stimulate the innovation motivation of enterprises, change the mode of economic growth and enter the stage of high-quality development has become the most urgent and realistic problem. The innovation activities of enterprises are inseparable from the effective support of financial resources. However, China′s financial system shows serious misallocation. This is worth studying how does financial misallocation in the market affect the innovation behavior of enterprises.Therefore, this paper introduces financial misallocation and other variables on the basis of the Matsuyama model and G-S model, systematically examines the impact mechanism of financial misallocation on corporate innovation and characterizes the model, and then proposes core propositions. Using the micro data of China′s listed companies from 2003 to 2018, based on the calculation of financial misallocation index, the above core propositions are verified from the dual perspective of policy distortion and financial friction. The results of the study found that financial misallocation companies have a significant "suppressive effect" on innovation, especially on companies that have "higher quality innovation patents". Further inspection revealed that financial mismatch will affect corporate innovation through two paths: policy distortion and financial friction.
        The research results of this paper have the following two contributions. First of all, this paper uses mathematical models and theoretical analysis to reveal to some extent the mechanism by which financial misallocation affect the innovation of Chinese enterprises, thereby providing new evidence for the innovation and development of Chinese enterprises. Secondly, from the dual perspective of policy distortion and financial market friction, the internal mechanism and transmission path of financial mismatch affecting corporate innovation is analyzed. The results of the study found that financial friction caused by imperfect market mechanisms and improper government intervention are the main ways to cause financial mismatches to inhibit corporate innovation and seriously inhibit the improvement of the quality of innovation in China. This provides a new perspective for the development of corporate innovation theory.
       The research conclusions of this paper have important implications for enhancing the enthusiasm of Chinese enterprises′ innovation activities. First of all, accelerating the marketization process of the financial system, promoting the rationalization and effectiveness of the allocation function of the financial market, reducing financial market friction, and trying to eliminate financial misallocation in the financial system. On the one hand, we continue to promote the reform of capital factor prices to form a reasonable capital factor price system, so that capital factor prices become a signal for the allocation of financial markets and improve finance. The efficiency of resource allocation creates a relatively fair competitive environment for companies of different ownerships and sizes, and strives to reduce financial frictions and ease external financing constraints faced by production activities of enterprises; on the other hand, by establishing multiple levels financial market system: increasing market access rate; developing inclusive finance to strengthen financial market construction; providing a broader development stage for the stock market and non-state-owned financial institutions; and promoting healthy and orderly competition among various entities in the financial market. Enterprises create more channels to access financial resources and promote innovation investment.
       Secondly, the government should change its position and function, reduce policy distortion and gradually withdraw from the national credit guarantee in the financial field, eliminate the preference of loan ownership of "meat rots in the pot" and "funds transfer from the left pocket to the right pocket", reduce ownership discrimination in the process of financial resource allocation, and create a reasonable financial ecological environment for enterprises. The government′s position should help state-owned enterprises to obtain low-cost capital, which should be transferred to encourage financial institutions to allocate more resources to non-state-owned enterprises, especially those with strong innovation ability and high demand for innovative capital, so as to reduce the mismatch of financial resources of enterprises and improve the innovation power of enterprises. 
        Finally, enterprises should strengthen their own capacity of financing. Compared with other activities, enterprise innovation activities have a high degree of uncertainty. This feature makes innovation contain information asymmetry and induce potential moral hazards, which leads to more severe external financing constraints faced by innovation activities. The financing constraints faced by enterprises are not only related to financial mismatches at the macro level, but also closely related to the construction of enterprises at the micro level in order to eliminate the gold caused by information asymmetry between enterprises and financial institutions to the greatest extent. In order to alleviate the external financing constraints and promote innovation, enterprises should strengthen the construction of their own credit system, establish and improve the information disclosure system, and reduce the risk of default caused by information asymmetry.
    References | Related Articles | Metrics
    The game dilemma and solution mechanism of the technological innovation subsidy performance supervision
    Wang Xingfen
    2022, 43(7): 77-84. 
    Abstract ( 107 )  
       As the performance of technological innovation subsidy has been of great immediate significance, it has gradually become an important realistic problem and issue. Under the background that innovation is going at the head of the development of global economy, it has attracted the attention of the whole world. The paper analyzed the deep reasons and the relative mechanisms which are the determining factors of the performance of technological innovation subsidy by using the non-cooperative game theory under different conditions and situations. Then it has been shown that the repeated cooperative game between the managers of a number of the enterprises and a few of the relative government officials has attained the balance mainly because of information asymmetry, self-interest tendency of enterprises and lack of supervision mechanism to the associate parties. The main reason is that the above officials who have the powers and duties of approval, examination and supervision could not be competent when they complete the normal mission of the State and the government. Just on account of that, the performance of technology innovation subsidy is not good or even cheating constantly in the meanwhile. And then they could even give rise to the insufficiency of innovation ability of the micro-enterprises, medium-sized industries and further macro economy of the whole country in the cause of time. 
        As a result, this paper put forward two main innovative ways and ideas to smooth away the above-mentioned difficulties and all kinds of troubles, even straitened circumstances. The first one is that at the static level, we hold the view that the best regulatory mechanisms to eradicate persistent diseases are that the scientifically and validly incentive mechanism should be adopted as soon as possible, only if most of the subsidized enterprises are part of the low-efficiency category of technological innovation activities. And in the meantime, the audit strategy of regulatory authority ought to be implemented promptly if both audit cost and optimal reward amount are in the lower level at this time. And yet, at the dynamic level, the relative policy-making department should try to set up the three-party non-cooperative repeat game mechanism, the dynamic evaluation system of subsidy performance, and the supervision and governance mechanism of multi-party coordination on and on in order to prevent the government from suffering any other additional losses. As a result, most of these losses are due to enterprises′ cheating for subsidies and any other inefficient, waste, inaction, and misbehavior activities of all of the above mentioned. 
       The main innovation of this paper is that the Dynamic Cooperative Game Theory is used to analyze the internal mechanism of illegal activities, such as cheating for subsidies, which affect the performance of technological innovation subsidy. This paper constructs some models to ensure the optimal performance of technological innovation subsidy and the maximization of enterprise and government objectives, makes an in-depth analysis of the optimal static and dynamic strategies of the two independent audits, and puts forward corresponding concrete suggestions.
    Related Articles | Metrics
    Construction and evolution of enterprise innovation network and breakthrough of key core technologies
    Zheng Gang, Deng Wanru, Wang Song, Zheng Jie
    2022, 43(7): 85-95. 
    Abstract ( 287 )  
       China′s chip industry has become one of the most prominent "strangleholding" areas in recent years. How Chinese chip enterprises break through the key core technology and establish an independent and controllable information technology industry system has become an important issue. The existing research on key core technologies (1) mainly discusses key core technologies′ connotation and development law from the technology perspective and (2) explores the key core technology breakthrough mechanism from the institutional perspective. However, they ignore the potential impact of systematic factors to a certain extent. The key core technology breakthrough is an extremely complex innovation activity, which requires cross-organizational and multi-dimensional coordination of technical and non-technical elements to form a virtuous circle.
        As an institutional arrangement formed in response to system innovation, enterprise innovation networks help enterprises integrate innovation resources and breakthrough technical barriers. Existing studies (1) mainly use resources as the intermediary to explore the impact of the characteristics of existing innovation networks on innovation results, and it believes that enterprises need to scan existing resources and opportunities to improve performance. (2) It defaults enterprises based on causal logic, by which decision-makers have rational goals, identify and find the most suitable partners, and plan the "effective" evolution of networks. However, suitable partners in the chip industry have a strong monopoly and exclusivity. It is difficult for latecomers to enter the existing network, with low knowledge acquisition and poor resource integration. In addition, key core technology breakthrough activities are long-term and uncertain, and future development is difficult to predict; the potential partners of enterprises are usually difficult to identify, which is difficult for enterprises to build networks only based on causal logic.
       The study of effectuation theory holds that in an uncertain environment, enterprises cannot make decisions based on rational goals but should follow the effectuation logic starting from a set of means as given and focusing on selecting between possible effects produced by using that set of means. This theory has more advantages in advocating value co-creation and effectively dealing with the impact of uncertainty than the causation logic characterized by "prediction and planning". Therefore, this paper attempts to introduce the effectuation theory and explore the internal law of phased breakthroughs in key core technologies of chip design based on a longitudinal case study of Loongson Technology Co., Ltd. with complete independent CPU design ability in China′s chip industry.
        The results show that: (1) breaking through the key core technology of "function-reliability-performance-compatibility", enterprises are facing a more complex and changeable network environment. Their resource stock and uncertain environment will affect their decision logic of networking and technological breakthrough. In this process, the decision logic evolves dynamically: in the early stage, it is mainly based on the effectuation logic, and in the later stage, it is based on the "causation-effectuation" comprehensive logic. (2) The construction and evolution of enterprise innovation networks go through a "leveraging-driving-linking" mechanism to integrate resources to break through the key core technology.
        The theoretical contribution lies in two aspects. Firstly, this paper introduces the effectuation theory, adapts the construction and evolution of enterprise networks to the antecedents of enterprise decision-making, summarizes the mechanism of enterprise to build innovation networks, and excavates the dynamic source of enterprise innovation network evolution. Secondly, based on the network perspective, this paper puts forward the mechanism model of enterprise innovation network construction in key core technology breakthroughs, provides a new interpretation framework for technology breakthroughs and promotes the relevant research.
        This paper has some practical managerial implications. (1) Enterprises should use the "leveraging-driving-linking" mechanism to build an innovation network, integrate the resources required for key core technology breakthroughs, take advantage of various opportunities brought by external uncertainty, and take technological innovation initiatives. (2) The government should also increase investment in industrial generic technological innovation activities and the construction of industrial network systems, strengthen policy support on the demand side, and provide enterprises with opportunities for trial-and-error iteration to improve their independent innovation capability.
    References | Related Articles | Metrics
    Research on the evolution characteristics and influencing factors of China′s innovation cooperation network——A study by taking the cooperation of SCI papers as an example
    Zhao Kangjie, Wu Yajun, Liu Xingchen
    2022, 43(7): 96-105. 
    Abstract ( 183 )  
       Under the background of implementing the innovation driven strategy and building an innovative country, integrating into the innovation cooperation network is an important way to enhance the regional innovation capacity of China's provinces. Based on the number of papers published in the core collection of web of science between China's provinces from 2008 to 2018, this paper uses the social network analysis method to construct China's provincial innovation cooperation network, and describes its temporal and spatial evolution characteristics from three aspects: network structure characteristics, network density characteristics and agglomerative subgroup analysis, From the perspective of proximity, this paper analyzes the impact mechanism of China's inter provincial innovation cooperation, and tests its robustness. This paper finds that the network structure of inter provincial innovation cooperation in China is becoming more complex and balanced. As time goes on, the links between the network nodes in China's innovation cooperation network are constantly enriched, and more and more node provinces occupy an important position in the network; The structure of China's innovation cooperation network has been continuously optimized, and the regional characteristics of the point degree centrality are obvious. The point degree centrality of each province has been improved in numerical value, and the order of the point degree centrality of most provinces is relatively stable. The middle centrality of each province is decreasing, and the ranking of middle centrality among provinces is changing greatly. Agglomerative subgroup analysis shows that geographical distance is an important factor affecting inter provincial innovation cooperation, and the close level of economic development between provinces is more conducive to innovation cooperation between the two provinces, and the number of agglomerative subgroups shows a downward trend. On the whole, the network characteristics of inter provincial innovation cooperation in China become more obvious, and the level of inter provincial innovation cooperation is constantly improving. This paper tests the impact mechanism of China's inter provincial innovation cooperation from the perspective of multi-dimensional proximity. The econometric test shows that improving network, industrial and economic proximity and shortening geographical distance are conducive to promoting China's inter provincial innovation cooperation, but network proximity and industrial proximity have the greatest impact on China's inter provincial innovation cooperation, while geographical proximity and economic proximity have less impact. Network proximity could influence the cooperation by adjusting geographical proximity and economic proximity. No matter random sampling or substitution econometric model, the robustness test results are consistent. Finally, this paper has some policy implications for the analysis of the characteristics and influence mechanism of China's inter provincial innovation cooperation. Three suggestions are put forward. First, China should focus on creating innovation growth poles in the central and western regions, and promote the balanced development of innovation network pattern. Secondly, each province should put forward ways to optimize innovation cooperation according to its own situation and local conditions. Third, the backward provinces can improve the innovation ecological environment to enhance the status of innovation network. Under the background of implementing the innovation-driven strategy and building an innovative country, integrating into the innovation cooperation network is an important way to enhance the regional innovation capacity of China′s provinces. Based on the number of papers published in the core collection of web of science between China′s provinces from 2008 to 2018, this paper uses the social network analysis method to construct China′s provincial innovation cooperation network, and describes its temporal and spatial evolution characteristics from three aspects: network structure, network density and agglomerative subgroup analysis. From the perspective of proximity, this paper analyzes the impact mechanism of China′s inter-provincial innovation cooperation, and tests its robustness.
        This paper finds that the network structure of inter-provincial innovation cooperation in China is becoming more complex and balanced. As time goes on, the links between the network nodes in China′s innovation cooperation network are constantly enriched, and more and more node provinces occupy an important position in the network. The structure of China′s innovation cooperation network has been continuously optimized, and the regional characteristics of the point degree centrality are obvious. The point degree centrality of each province has been improved in numerical value, and the order of the point degree centrality of most provinces is relatively stable. The middle centrality of each province is decreasing, and the ranking of middle centrality among provinces is changing greatly. Agglomerative subgroup analysis shows that geographical distance is an important factor affecting inter-provincial innovation cooperation, and the close level of economic development between provinces is more conducive to innovation cooperation between the two provinces, and the number of agglomerative subgroups shows a downward trend. On the whole, the network characteristics of inter-provincial innovation cooperation in China become more obvious, and the level of inter-provincial innovation cooperation is constantly improving.
        This paper tests the impact mechanism of China′s inter-provincial innovation cooperation from the perspective of multi-dimensional proximity. The econometric test shows that improving network, industrial and economic proximity and shortening geographical distance are conducive to promoting China′s inter-provincial innovation cooperation, but network proximity and industrial proximity have the greatest impact on China′s inter-provincial innovation cooperation, while geographical proximity and economic proximity have less impact. Network proximity could influence the cooperation by adjusting geographical proximity and economic proximity. No matter random sampling or substitution econometric model, the robustness test results are consistent.
        Finally, this paper has some policy implications for the analysis of the characteristics and influence mechanism of China′s inter-provincial innovation cooperation. Three suggestions are put forward. First, China should focus on creating innovation growth poles in the central and western regions, and promote the balanced development of innovation network pattern. Secondly, each province should put forward ways to optimize innovation cooperation according to its own situation and local conditions. Third, the backward provinces can improve the innovation ecological environment to enhance the status of innovation network.
    References | Related Articles | Metrics
    Research on the mutual eating process between corporate social responsibility and business model innovation
    Wang Xuedong
    2022, 43(7): 106-114. 
    Abstract ( 133 )  
       Corporate social responsibility (CSR) and business model innovation have always been hot topics in the field of business management. CSR has a positive impact on business model innovation, and business model innovation provides an economic base for enterprises to fulfill their social responsibility, as though the combination of the two has become a theoretical consensus. However, there is a significant conflict between this theoretical consensus and the actual business practices we have observed. Companies such as Pangda Group, Huishan Dairy Group, Wanda Group, and China Fortune Land Development Group have incorporated the concepts of CSR, deeply practiced CSR, and radically implemented business model innovation, but end up with a co-destruction of business model and CSR. The co-destruction of CSR and business model innovation is a new phenomenon that needs in-depth analysis. Therefore, we have derived two research questions: (1) how does the co-destruction of CSR and business model innovation occur and develop? (2) what is the relationship between CSR and business model innovation in this process? 
        In view of this, this paper adopts the multiple case study method, taking four companies including Pangda Group, Wanda Group, Huishan Dairy and China Fortune Fortune as the study objects, and it also conduct a longitudinal case study to analyze the co-destruction of CSR and business model innovation. This research contributes to existing literature of CSR by unpacking the process of mutual eating and its interactions, as well as the interactive relationship between them. This research also has practical implications for companies to implement CSR and business model innovation more pragmatically and rationally.
         The results of the research are as follow: Firstly, we have identified the process of mutual eating between CSR and business model innovation, including three stages: attachment phase, mutual absorption phase and co-destruction phase. In the attachment period, the success of business model innovation causes the implementation of CSR by third-party organizations. In the mutual absorption period, CSR honor triggers entrepreneurs′ scale preference, resulting in the replication of business model. Success of business model replication further strengthens the stakeholder′s CSR adherence, forming a positive interaction between CSR and business model innovation. In the mutual phagocytic period, the out-of-control of entrepreneurs causes disorderly expansion of firms, which in turn triggers the collapse of business models, causing major CSR accidents, and the co-destruction of CSR and business model innovation. 
        Secondly, our research also identified a double-edged sword effect between CSR and business model innovation. CSR accelerates the pace of business model innovation and also enlarges the risks. Business model innovation provides an economic basis for CSR performance, but uncontrollable business model innovation can also bring huge CSR disasters. Thirdly, entrepreneurs play a bridge role between CSR and business model innovation. Entrepreneurial scale preference triggers the mutual attraction between CSR and business model innovation, but entrepreneurs losing rational judgment cause the co-destruction of CSR and business model innovation.
          This research makes several theoretical contributions to the existing literature as follows. First, it describes the co-destruction of CSR and business model innovation, fully uncovers the dark side of CSR, and reconciles the conflict between theory and practice. Second, it summarizes the process of interaction between CSR and business model innovation from the perspective of process, and unpacks the black box of double-edged sword effects between them. Third, it reveals the unique bridge role of entrepreneurs, and provides new insights for understanding CSR and business model innovation.
         The findings also provide some practical implications for Chinese entrepreneurs, especially private entrepreneurs and government agencies. First, entrepreneurs should give full play to the positive role of CSR in business model innovation, and use CSR′s reputation mechanism to amplify the brand awareness and reputation of their company, so as to better integrate with stakeholders, remove the hindrance and accelerate the pace of business model innovation. Second, entrepreneurs should avoid the dark side of CSR during the process of business model innovation, pay attention to the scale preference induced by third-party CSR adherence and stakeholder promotion, always maintain objective and cautious during business model innovation, and avoid losing control during expanding. Finally, government departments or industry institutions should establish an authoritative corporate social responsibility evaluation mechanism to create a favorable corporate social responsibility business environment for entrepreneurs and executives to start businesses, and preventing unethical media and organizations from seeking ill-gotten wealth in the name of CSR.
        Although this paper selected the four most representative and typical companies for objects of case study, it is recommended here due to the limitations of the study to further validate and testify the results obtained from the study through a quantitative empirical analysis in the future research to improve the generalizability.
    References | Related Articles | Metrics
    Has industrial structure adjustment promoted regional innovation performance?
    Han Jun, Kong Lingcheng
    2022, 43(7): 115-123. 
    Abstract ( 132 )  
        Since the international financial crisis in 2008, the world economy has entered the period of profound adjustment. Industries are fiercely competitive among countries around the world and the developed countries have put forward the strategy of "industrialization", trying to promote the manufacture level of industrial technology innovation and the development of emerging industries and continue to control firmly technology innovation and professional services industry value chain link through adjustment of industrial structure in the new platform. As the largest developing country in the world, China has achieved the transformation from a weak country to an economic power. In the process of this transformation, structural contradictions in China′s industrial layout have become increasingly prominent. Industries with high energy consumption, high pollution and low efficiency still account for a large proportion in China′s industrial system. It works in the short term but it is an unsustainable development model in the long term. Its malpractice already began to show in China, and there are many reasons for this kind of unreasonable industrial structure. Therefore, it is urgent to adjust the industrial structure, change the mode of economic growth, improve the capacity of independent innovation and build China into an innovation-oriented country.
        The 18th National Congress of the Communist Party of China pointed out that the strategic adjustment of industrial structure fosters new economic growth points, and improves the independent innovation ability of innovative countries. With China′s economic growth into the new normal, the implementation of national innovation-driven development strategy, the high-quality economic development, and industrial structure adjustment and innovation have become important drivers of high-quality economic development, and the adjustment of China′s industrial structure in the coming period is a more difficult task. In this context, industrial structure adjustment is not only the support force of sustainable development of the national economy, but also an important way to enhance the transformation of independent innovation, enabling China to grow from an innovative power to an innovative power. As China′s economic growth has entered a new normal and the country′s innovation-driven development has been put forward, the task of adjusting the industrial structure has become more arduous. Based on this background, this paper adopts the data of industrial enterprises above the scale from 1998 to 2017 to construct the structural adjustment range and quality index of industrial enterprises respectively. From the perspective of industrial structure adjustment range and quality of industrial structure adjustment, it examines whether industrial structure adjustment promotes the improvement of regional innovation performance.
        The results show that: (1) The adjustment of industrial structure has a significant effect on regional innovation performance, and it is found that the adjustment range and quality of industrial structure have heterogeneity on inter-regional innovation performance. (2) Significant spatial spillover effect exists in the adjustment of industrial structure. This spillover effect exists in the whole country and has an inhibitory effect on regional innovation performance. It is found that there are regional differences in spatial spillovers. The quality of industrial structure adjustment in the eastern and central regions has a restraining effect on the spatial spillover effect of innovation performance, while the industrial structure adjustment in the western regions has a promoting effect on the spatial spillover effect of innovation performance. (3) Industrial structure adjustment has threshold effect on regional innovation performance. The adjustment range of industrial structure has a single threshold on the regional innovation performance, and the quality of industrial structure adjustment has a double threshold effect on the regional innovation performance. Only when the two have crossed the threshold value can their positive effects on the innovation performance be transformed into the driving force of innovation. 
        Based on the above conclusions, this paper has the following policy implications: (1) Due to regional resource endowments and regional economic development level differences, different regions in the process of industrial structure adjustment should take advantage of the present industrial development in this region and its regional resources, adjust and optimize continuously the industrial transfer in the process of resource redistribution, so as to realize the coordinative development of industrial structure adjustment and innovation performance. (2) As the market mechanism cannot compensate and correct the economic externalities, the government needs to use "visible hand" to solve the market failure and establish a strong policy mechanism to promote innovation performance in the process of macro-industrial structure regulation and control policies. (3) In the adjustment process of industrial structure in different regions, the adjustment should be carefully treated, so as to avoid distortion of the allocation of production factors in space and between industries, and prevent the overcorrection from inhibiting the improvement of regional innovation performance.
    Related Articles | Metrics
    Digital economy, regional soft environment and formation of technology transfer network
    Zhang Xixi, Dong Yao, Yi Tao
    2022, 43(7): 124-134. 
    Abstract ( 190 )  
       In recent years, China′s digital economy has achieved leapfrog development and it is becoming a new engine for high-quality economic development. The update and iteration of digital technology boost the development of technological production and transfer mode to scientific and intelligent, the boundaries of regional economic activities are weakening, and the cost of acquiring knowledge and information in the network has also decreased significantly. Technology transfer has strong externalities and network effects, deeply embedded in the regional innovation environment. Regional innovation environment can be divided into soft environment and hard environment. The disequilibrium of the hard environment in regional space leads to the heterogeneous orientation of the technology transfer network, while the soft environment can be changed by human intervention in a short time and has an impact on regional technology transfer activities.
        Judging from the existing research literature, the formation mechanism of the technology transfer network is analyzed qualitatively from different perspectives. The relevant research results of digital economy, regional soft environment and technology transfer provide important reference for this paper. However, the research on whether the digital economy can drive the formation of the regional technology transfer network is relatively few and there is still room for expansion. This also provides an opportunity to make marginal contributions to this paper. Firstly, this paper explores the influence of digital economy on the formation of technology transfer network at the regional level through point-to-point data of technology transfer. We discuss the relationship between digital economy and technology transfer from the perspective of digital economy compatibility and digital economy development level, and expand the research space of digital economy enabling technology transfer at the regional level. Secondly, from the five aspects of government governance environment, legal environment, financial environment, technology environment and market environment, the paper quantitatively describes the influence of regional soft environment on technology transfer network, providing empirical evidence for optimization of regional soft environment and realizing "Overtaking on curves" in technology transfer. Thirdly, digital economy development and regional soft environment factors are incorporated in the study of the technology transfer network, which enriches the relevant theories of determinants of technology transfer.
       This study uses patent rights transfer data to construct an inter-regional technology transfer network, and analyzes the local structure of the network with Motifs Analysis method. The influence of digital economy and regional soft environment on the formation of the technology transfer network is explored by using the Exponential Random Graph Models (ERGM). The results show that the technology transfer pattern is mutually beneficial and it has poor network transitivity. The development of the digital economy stimulates the prosperity of regional technology transfer. But the development difference of the digital economy leads to "Richman′s Club" and the dilemma of "technology island" in the technology transfer network, which will further deepen the technology gap between regions. Among the regional soft environment factors, legal environment, technological environment, government governance environment and financial environment have different degrees of positive effect on technology transfer. The market environment positively moderates the impact of the digital economy on technology transfer, and when the market environment is better, the digital economy plays a more significant role in promoting regional technology transfer.
       As an organic component of the regional innovation system, technology transfer is the power source of regional innovation ecological evolution. Based on a series of empirical evidence that digital economy and regional soft environment promote the formation of technology transfer network obtained in this study, we draw three implications for improving regional technology transfer: (1) Accelerate the development of 5G commercial, artificial intelligence and other advanced digital technology, and consolidate the advantages of the digital technology. Enterprises in regions with digital disadvantages will be subsidized for digital investment to enhance the accessibility of digital economy and narrow the regional "technology gap". (2) Establish a digital single market for technology trading to break the fragmentation of the technology trading system. Besides, it can also provide technology demand matching and scientific research resource matching services for technology subjects, which will improve the efficiency and breadth of technology demand matching. (3) More attention should be paid to improving the government governance environment, increasing transfer payments to less developed regions, and implementing post-incentive subsidies for technology transfer. At the same time, the government also pays attention to the construction of digital rule of law to improve the regional legal environment, and digitally writes the technology transfer process into smart contracts to ensure that the technology transfer process is transparent and traceable. Improve the risk compensation management of technology transfer loans, stimulate the technology transfer activity of enterprises in the region in the form of special funds and financial support.
    Related Articles | Metrics
    Core technology, complementary assets and  beyond catch-up for latecomer firms
    Peng Xinmin, Wu Xiaobo, Wu Dong
    2022, 43(7): 135-143. 
    Abstract ( 173 )  
        For latecomer firms, core technology and complementary assets represent two different catch-up strategies, however, latecomer firms often face the dilemma of how to choose and balance the two strategies as relatively resources scarce. Different from the initial catch-up in the secondary innovation stage, in the process of beyond catch-up from the secondary innovation to the original innovation, latecomer firms begin to approach and challenge the industry leaders,which need to innovate in a constantly changing competitive environment where there are few opportunities for direct imitation. However, there is a lack of research on the evolution mechanism of the post-secondary innovation to the original innovation.
        Additionally, the existing research on the relationship between core technology and complementary assets mainly focus on incumbents in developed economies, lacking a catch-up perspective based on latecomers. In particular, the interaction between core technology and complementary assets is still unclear in the context of new technological change in which Chinese latecomer firms are in the beyond catch-up phase. Therefore, the research question of this paper is how to choose and balance the two strategies of core technology and complementary assets for latecomer firms in the dynamic process of beyond catch-up from the secondary innovation to the original innovation?
        The research question in this paper involve the detailed process of "how", and the case study is suitable for answering questions like "how" and "why", so the longitudinal single case study method is chosen. This paper chooses the beyond catch-up process of Haitian Plastic Machine Group CO., LTD (hereinafter abbreviated as "Haitian") in the field of all-electric injection molding machine technology as the object of the case study. In this research, a variety of different data collection methods, such as personnel interview, literature materials and archival records, are adopted to ensure that the research data were mutually supplemented and cross-verified through diversified research information and data sources, so as to ensure the reliability and validity of the research. The data analysis process of this paper also follows the process of inductive case studies. 
        Through the case study of Haitian′s catch-up in the field of all-electric injection molding machine technology from 2001 to 2017, this paper finds that in the secondary innovation stage, latecomer firms have experienced the transformation of catch-up strategy from core technology dominance to complementary asset dominance, which not only breaks through the core technology, but also gains market revenue. In the original innovation stage, latecomer firms adopt the strategy of pursuing both core technology and complementary assets, that is, on the one hand, they carry out core technology research and development by capturing the windows of opportunity brought by changes in market demand; on the other hand, they gain innovation benefits through complementary assets, which ultimately promotes the joint improvement of their technological capabilities and market performance. Therefore, from the perspective of organizational ambidexterity, in the dynamic process of beyond catch-up from the post-secondary innovation to the original innovation, the catch-up strategy of latecomer firms has undergone the evolution from the punctuated balance of core technology and complementary assets to the ambidextrous balance in which both are equally valued.
        This study has theoretical contributions in the following three aspects. First of all, this study deepens our understanding of the dynamics of latecomers catch-up. In the dynamic process of beyond catch-up from the post-secondary innovation to the original innovation, the core technology and complementary assets show the characteristics of interactive evolution, realizing dynamic alternations in the dimension of time and space, following the evolution process from punctuated balance mode to the ambidextrous balance mode, and finally enabling the latecomers to achieve beyond catch-up. Therefore, this discovery reveals the beyond catch-up mechanism of latecomer firms from the secondary innovation to the original innovation, deepens our understanding of beyond catch-up.
        Secondly, this study also enriches the theory of complementary assets. From the perspective of catch-up of latecomer firms, this paper investigates the leading role and evolution characteristics of complementary asset construction and core technology R&D in latecomers′ catch-up, and finds that from the secondary innovation to the original innovation, the complementary asset construction and core technology research and development follow the transformation from punctuated balance to ambidextrous balance. This conclusion enriches the research situation of complementary assets from the perspective of catch-up and helps to further understand the dynamic relationship between complementary assets and technology R&D.
        Finally, this study also expands the ambidexterity theory. This paper finds that the strategic balance between complementary assets and technology R&D of latecomers belongs to the cross-domain balance between market and technology, that is, the ambidextrous balance can be realized through cross-domain. Further, the realization mode of enterprise ambidextrous balance is dynamic changing, from the secondary innovation to original innovation, latecomer firms balance explorative and exploitative activities through different modes, in the secondary innovation stage, punctuated balance is achieved; in the original innovation stage, ambidextrous balance is achieved. The discovery that the ambidextrous pattern evolves from sequence to synchronic in the process of beyond catch-up deepens our understanding of the dynamics of organizational ambidextrous balance.
        This paper also provides relevant empirical enlightenment for the latecomer firms at the stage of beyond catch-up. First, latecomer firms should build up their R&D capabilities quickly at the beyond catch-up phase. They should be highly sensitive to the windows of opportunity of emerging technologies, and cut into the field of emerging technologies as quickly as possible to build the R&D capacity of new technologies, and timely build key proprietary complementary assets to accelerate the evolution cycle of secondary innovation and realize the evolution of original innovation. Second, latecomer firms should continue to develop competitive manufacturing capabilities. If a series of manufacturing complementary assets associated with mature technologies are also valuable for alternative emerging technologies, latecomer firms can combine global management skills to develop competitive manufacturing complementary assets and provide customized products or services for customers. Finally, latecomer firms should fully recognize the strategic significance of market-specific complementary assets. Market-specific complementary assets, such as developing and mastering new brands, foreign distribution and service channels, can enable latecomer firms to grasp the channels and capabilities to provide their own products and services to final users and gain the opportunity to learn from leading users. 
    References | Related Articles | Metrics
    Research on the influence mechanism of technology market on collaborative innovation based on the theory of market design——A study by taking high-tech enterprises as an example
    Yu Liping, Wang Bing
    2022, 43(7): 144-153. 
    Abstract ( 141 )  
       Collaborative innovation is an important mode of enterprise innovation, which is influenced by the technology market environment. Collaborative innovation can fully mobilize innovation resources and improve the efficiency and quality of innovation resources. Technology market is an important place for high-tech enterprises to trade technology commodities. The development of technology market can drive the development of innovation and promote collaborative innovation. Strengthening the cultivation and development of technology market can optimize the innovation environment of high-tech enterprises and promote the transformation of scientific and technological achievements. Based on market design theory and collaborative innovation theory, it is of great theoretical and practical value to study technology market fluency and technology market thickness for collaborative innovation. Based on the relevant data of the statistical yearbook of China′s high-tech industry from 2009 to 2016, this paper studies the linear and nonlinear effects of technology market fluency and technology market thickness on corporate collaborative innovation, as well as the interaction mechanism among the three.
       It can be analyzed that the effect mechanism of technology market fluency and technology market thickness on corporate collaborative innovation from general perspective and life cycle perspective. From a general perspective, technology market fluency promotes collaborative innovation through information media, innovation intermediary level and identification of technology resources, while the technology market thickness plays a role in collaborative innovation through market pull effect and push effect. From a life cycle perspective, when the high-tech market is in the initial stage, with low market thickness and market fluency, small and micro enterprises are faced with great pressure for innovation, and they are difficult to find collaborative innovation partners and market for technology products. Although large and medium-sized enterprises have strong strength, because the technology market is not developed enough, it will reduce the speed and quality of collaborative innovation. When the high-tech market enters the growth stage, the market thickness and market fluency develop rapidly, the collaborative innovation of some small and micro enterprises is still greatly affected, but the effect on large and medium-sized enterprises is little. When the high-tech market enters the mature stage, the technology market is mature, with high market thickness and market fluency, it has a positive effect on the collaborative innovation of all enterprises. On the other hand, from both perspectives, collaborative innovation has a certain feedback mechanism on technology market fluency and technology market thickness.
        On the basis of analyzing the influence mechanism of technology market fluency and technology market thickness on corporate collaborative innovation, four hypotheses are proposed. Hypothesis 1: Technology market fluency has a positive contribution to corporate collaborative innovation. Hypothesis 2: The elasticity of technology market fluency to corporate collaborative innovation is decreasing. With the improvement of corporate collaborative innovation level, the elasticity of technology market fluency to corporate collaborative innovation is decreasing. Hypothesis 3: The effect of technology market thickness on corporate collaborative innovation is not significant. Hypothesis 4: The contribution of technology market thickness to corporate collaborative innovation has the threshold effect of corporate collaborative innovation. When corporate collaborative innovation is up to a high level, the elasticity of technology market thickness to corporate collaborative innovation is the highest.
       Besides, this paper studies the interaction between technology market fluency, technology market thickness and corporate collaborative innovation through panel data model, panel threshold model, Granger causality test and panel vector auto regression model. The panel data model is used to analyze the static linear relationship between them, the panel threshold model is used to analyze the nonlinear relationship between them, the Granger causality test and the panel vector auto regression model are used to analyze their interaction.
        The empirical results show that first of all, the technology market thickness is not conducive to corporate collaborative innovation. Although China′s technology market and collaborative innovation have made great progress and development, the overall technology market still needs to be further cultivated and developed, and the average level of corporate collaborative innovation still needs to be improved. On the one hand, the effect of technology market thickness is not obvious when the level of collaborative innovation is not high. On the other hand, because the technology market thickness itself depends on the number of technology transactions, if the technology market is not cultivated enough, cultivation quality is not high and the protection of intellectual property rights is weak, the enthusiasm of enterprises for technology transactions may be affected. 
        Secondly, the technology market fluency can promote corporate collaborative innovation. The technology market fluency often depends on the government′s science and technology policy, which indicates that the existing government science and technology policy for the technology market is relatively perfect. 
        Thirdly, the technology market thickness has long-term effects on corporate collaborative innovation, the development of technology market thickness is entering a transition period, it shows that the elasticity of technology market thickness to corporate collaborative innovation is not significant, but the long-term dynamic effect is better, this fully shows that China is entering the threshold of the rapid development of technology market, once across the stage, it will have a long-term positive effect on the collaborative innovation. 
        Fourthly, the technology market fluency has a significant short-term effect on corporate collaborative innovation. The technology market fluency essentially reflects the management level of the technology market. When the government formulate technology market management policy, they must pay attention to the long-term mechanism of the policy, which should not only have short-term effect, but also be more conducive to the management of technology market in the long run. 
       Fifthly, the feedback effect of collaborative innovation on the technology market fluency is greater than the technology market thickness. It indicates that when the level of corporate collaborative innovation improves, it is relatively easy to promote the technology market fluency. From the perspective of management, it is relatively fast to introduce policies, and the effect is better. However, the improvement of technology market thickness requires the majority of enterprises to carry out technology innovation, which is difficult to have an effect in the short term, but in the long run, the effect will be more significant.
    Related Articles | Metrics
    The power of structure: A study of the impact of strategic alliance network on firm′s technological innovation
    Yang Zhangbo, Wang Qin
    2022, 43(7): 154-162. 
    Abstract ( 147 )  
       In order to meet the requirements of open innovation, firms in the high-tech industry will actively seek external partners and establish strategic alliances. An alliance is an inter-organizational cooperative relationship governed by a formal contract, which involves the exchange of resources and knowledge, organizational commitment and joint development. Firms′ strategic alliance partners will also form alliance relationships with other kinds of organizations, including government, universities and public research organizations. These different organizations and the alliance relationships between each other form the strategic network. 
        A large number of studies have shown that the strategic alliance network will affect the technological innovation performance of firms. Organizations can obtain certain resources from the embedded network for internal technological innovation activities, and there are mainly three different types of resources: resources, knowledge and information obtained directly by partners through their own alliances. For the focal firm, the strategic network has structural advantages, as well as intangible benefits such as power, reputation and trust that the focal firm can obtain from the whole network. The impact of the network on innovation can be understood as how the composition of the network and the structure of the network affect the focal firm′s technological innovation. The impact of network structure on the technological innovation performance of enterprises is more complicated. There are two different mechanisms for the impact of interorganizational network structure on firm performance: network closure and network openness. However, current empirical research does not have a stable conclusion, which may be because the theoretical boundary is not clear. 
       This paper argues that which mechanism works depends on the innovation tasks that the firm faces and whether the source of knowledge is within the boundaries of ego network. Bases on three firm level databases: Recap, USPTO and Compustat, we construct a longitude data of biotechnology and pharmaceutical industry from 1990 to 2001. We use social network analysis method, fixed effect model and random effect model to test our hypotheses. The findings suggest that increase of density of strategic network and increase of structural holes index has a negative influence on firm′s technological innovation quantity and a positive influence on firm′s technological innovation quality. We also found network structure has a moderating effect on the relation between direct/indirect ties and innovation outcomes. In detail, in a dense and closed network, the increase in direct connections will have a positive impact on the quality of innovation and the quantity of innovation outcomes; the increase in indirect connections will have a negative impact on the quality of innovation and the quantity of innovation outcomes. In a sparse, open network, the positive impact of increased direct connections on innovation quantity and innovation quality will weaken; the negative impact of increased indirect connections on innovation quality will also weaken. 
       Based on the existing analysis, this research further reveals the complex relationship between network structure and innovation. The main points are as follows: First, the nature of the innovation task determines how structural holes affect the technological innovation of an enterprise. The role of structural holes in organizational technological innovation has been controversial, and current studies showed both negative empirical results and positive results. This research provides a way to measure the innovation output of firms using multiple indicators rather than only patent numbers, and found that the inconsistency of structural holes effects on technological innovation depends on the inconsistency of innovation tasks. It allows us to better understand the relationship between structural holes and innovation. Secondly, existing studies have mostly analyzed the impact of network structure on innovation from the perspective of ego networks and direct connections, ignoring the embeddedness of enterprises in the global network. We find that, within the boundaries of ego networks, the effects of the network structure can be analyzed from two aspects: intra-network effects and extra-network effects. The effects of the two are different: closed networks are more conducive to the use of exploitive search, which is mainly reflected in the problem-solving process of the focal firm, thereby improving the benefits that the firm obtains from direct ties; on the other hand, the open network is conducive to the firm′s exploratory search, helping the focal firm to acquire more new knowledge, thereby increasing the benefits that the focal firm can get from indirect ties. Finally, this research design adopts the perspective of dynamic networks, focusing on the impact of changes in network structure characteristics on technological innovation, breaking the pre-assumed assumption of static networks. Based on panel data, the paper is able to examine the impact of changes in network characteristics on technological innovation outcomes of enterprises. Existing studies have mostly analyzed the impact of static network indicators on the number of technological innovations in a particular year rather than the effects of network dynamic. 
        This research also has some implications for the practice of corporate strategic alliance networks. First, corporate managers should not only care about who they are allied with, but also the relationships between their alliance partners, and even the indirect relationship between alliance partners and third parties. These connections construct the network structure. Second, managers should also consider whether the network the firm embedded in is dense, closed, or sparse and open. Third, when analyzing the impact of an embedded network on their own companies, managers must not only focus on the positive effects of the network, but also the negative effects of the network.
    Related Articles | Metrics
    The effect of relationship network on organizational resilience: The mediating role of ambidextrous innovation
    Zhang Mengtao, Zhang Shengtai
    2022, 43(7): 163-170. 
    Abstract ( 293 )  
       Under the "new normal" of future development with the characteristics of VUCA in the market, the frequent occurrence of "black Swan" and "gray rhino" events has changed the original business model and organizational type of enterprises. Whether enterprises can form resilience and grow against the trend under the impact of adverse events has become the key to their survival and turning crisis into opportunities. Despite the potential threats posed by adversity, highly capable teams and other relational systems embedded in organizations can generate positive outcomes and facilitate a return to (or improvement upon) the status quo.
        In view of the lack of attention paid to the formation mechanism of organizational resilience in current empirical studies, this paper explores the internal mechanism of relationship network and organizational resilience from both intra-organizational and inter-organizational perspectives. By the establishment of the structural equation model, this paper discusses whether and how relationship network affects organizational resilience. Specifically, we investigated the mediating role of dual innovation (exploratory innovation and exploitative innovation) in the relationship between relationship network and organizational resilience. Questionnaire surveys were conducted among companies in Beijing, Tianjin and Hebei to serve as an empirical sample. SPSS and AMOS were conducted to test the hypotheses.
        The empirical analysis results show that intra-organizational and inter-organizational relationship networks are positively correlated with organizational resilience. Intra-organizational relationship network positively affects exploitative innovation and inter-organizational relationship network positively affects exploratory innovation. Exploitive innovation plays a partially mediating role between intra-organizational relationship network and organizational resilience. Exploratory innovation partially mediates the relationship between interorganizational network and organizational resilience. The results reveal the role of dual innovation (exploratory innovation and exploitative innovation) in the relationship network (intra-organizational relationship network and inter-organizational relationship network) on organizational resilience. Our research findings have not only made contributions to the studies on the relation among the relationship network, dual innovation, organizational resilience, but also have practical significance for business managers effectively improving organizational resilience.
       Our findings contribute to the practice of management in several ways. Firstly, managers should coordinate the relationship between network organization members, to create conditions for coordination and communication within the organization departments, to promote the sharing of information. In addition, managers should pay attention to the building of relationship network between organizations, actively mobilize non-market resources and win the support of stakeholders, in order to establish the channels to obtain heterogeneous resources organization members, the opportunity to contact new external knowledge. Secondly, managers can comprehensively consider and coordinate the key role of exploratory innovation and exploitative innovation in the development of enterprises. Managers should provide professional technology, equipment and other support for employees, and give appropriate external incentives to encourage employees to participate in exploitative innovation activities such as expanding existing markets, utilizing existing resources and improving existing technologies. In addition, while encouraging employees to carry out exploratory innovation activities, managers should give them sufficient support and enough psychological security, so as to create a good organizational innovation atmosphere for employees and alleviate their behavioral concerns caused by risk avoidance in exploratory innovation activities.
    Related Articles | Metrics
    A study of the project financing performance on the cultural creativity platform
    Zhang Hong, Song Da′e, Wang Xinxin
    2022, 43(7): 171-180. 
    Abstract ( 141 )  
       As an emerging Internet finance model, crowdfunding provides new marketing methods and financing channels for start-ups and individual entrepreneurs. As a new engine for the integrated development of the Internet economy and the real economy, the crowdfunding platform has huge market potential. However, the amount of project financing growth is slow or even negative, and the project financing failure rate is as high as 50%. Therefore, how to meet the value needs of potential investors and improve the financing success rate is a practical problem that crowdfunding platforms and project sponsors need to solve urgently. At the same time, the research on the crowdfunding platform in the existing literature mainly analyzes the influencing factors of the project financing performance from the four aspects of the basic characteristics of the project, fundraisers, funders, and crowdfunding platforms. Refining the basic characteristics of the project is still in the exploratory stage. The cultural creativity crowdfunding platform, as a typical innovation ecosystem, the projects on the platform are regarded as an innovative product or service, and its innovation characteristics are more prominent. Therefore, this paper focuses on the cultural creativity crowdfunding platform, based on the theory of innovation diffusion to theoretically abstract the characteristics of crowdfunding projects, construct an impact mechanism model of innovation project diffusion, and explore the moderating effects of project status and sponsor information disclosure in this impact mechanism. First, based on the positive impact of innovation characteristics stated in the theory of innovation diffusion on the results of innovation diffusion, it is proposed that the relative advantage, compatibility and observability characteristics of crowdfunding projects positively affect the financing performance of crowdfunding projects. Second, considering that the status of the crowdfunding project will affect the user′s decision-making reference model, it is proposed that the crowdfunding status (in the crowdfunding and the success of the crowdfunding) will adjust the relative advantage, compatibility and observability characteristics of the crowdfunding project positive impact of financing performance. Finally, considering the positive emotional response caused by the information disclosure of the initiator, it is proposed that the information disclosure of the initiator will positively regulate the positive impact of the relative advantage, compatibility and observability characteristics of the crowdfunding project on project financing performance.
        In this study, MoDian website, a representative cultural creativity crowdfunding platform is taken as the research object. We collected online data from the establishment date of the website to October 7, 2018, and analyzed and tested the model by using the STATA14.0 tool. According to the research, it is shown that, primarily, relative advantage and compatibility have a positive impact on project financing performance; there was no significant impact between observability and project financing performance. In addition, the location of the project, the type of support amount, the number of projects initiated by the initiator, and the number of projects supported by the initiator all positively affect the project financing performance, while the target amount, the number of projects that the initiator is concerned about, and the number of creative ideas that the initiator is optimistic about negatively affect the project financing performance. Then, project status has a positive impact in regulating the relationship between project financing performance and relative advantage, and negatively influence the regulation of the relationship between project financing performance and observability. What′s more, for the relationship between compatibility and project financing performance, the project status has no significant impact on their relationship. Sponsor information disclosure plays a positive role in the relation between project financing performance and comparative advantage, and negatively influence the relationship between compatibility, observability and project financing performance.
        The research has made some theoretical contributions. Firstly, the impact mechanism model of innovation diffusion constructed in this paper has detailed the research on the influencing factors of crowdfunding project financing performance. Secondly, this paper analyzes the impact of relative advantage, compatibility, and observability on the financing performance of crowdfunding projects, and provides a new theoretical perspective for research in the field of crowdfunding. Finally, this paper sets project status and initiator information disclosure as moderators, explores its moderating effect on the relationship between innovation characteristics and project financing performance. The dual perspectives of the sponsor and the initiator reveal the boundary conditions of the impact mechanism model of crowdfunding project diffusion. 
    References | Related Articles | Metrics
    Analyst optimism bias and corporate R&D investment: An empirical study based on conflicts of interest and transparency of information
    Dong Zhu, Zhang Xin
    2022, 43(7): 181-188. 
    Abstract ( 206 )  
        Innovation is the primary driving force behind development. In the current period, China′s scientific and technological innovation has become the focus of world attention. Faced with the squeeze and competition from the "First Group" countries such as the United States, Japan and European countries, the construction of an innovative country has entered a decisive stage. As a basic guarantee for the continuous development of innovation activities, R&D investment is essential to promote corporate innovation. In 2017, the intensity of China′s R&D expenditure (ratio to GDP) reached 2.15%, but there was still a gap compared with the level of 2.5%-4% in major developed countries. In recent years, how to increase R&D investment has attracted extensive attention from the academic community. 
        We focus on the impact of analysts as information intermediaries in the capital market on R&D investment of enterprises. Although analysts can reduce the degree of information asymmetry between company and outside, they will also increase the pressure on short-term performance goals of company. According to the information interpretation mechanism, analysts rely on their professional information collection, processing, and analysis capabilities to communicate the intrinsic value of the company through profit forecasting and rating reports, reducing the information asymmetry between external investors and the company, and alleviating the company′s financing constraints and entrusted agency issues, thereby increasing the company′s R&D investment and promoting corporate innovation; according to the performance pressure mechanism, the analyst′s job content is to predict and evaluate the short-term performance of the company, which will cause performance pressure on managers, and due to concerns about their reputation, wealth, and career development, managers will reduce long-term innovation investment in order to pursue short-term performance goals, reduce corporate R&D investment, and inhibit corporate innovation. Therefore, the existing literature on the impact of analysts on corporate R&D innovation has not yet reached a consensus conclusion. In addition, existing studies have shown that analysts′ predictions are generally biased by optimism, subject to conflicts of interest such as underwriting business, increasing commission income, and maintaining customer relationships.
       Based on this, this paper studies the impact of analyst optimism bias on corporate R&D investment, the role of conflicts of interest in it, and the role of corporate information transparency. Specifically, this paper selects A-share listed companies with R&D expenditures in Shanghai and Shenzhen in 2007-2017 as a sample to empirically test the relationship between analyst optimism bias and corporate R&D investment, and further examine the impact of the "conflict of interest" of analysts and corporate information transparency on this relationship. The research results show that: (1) the analyst′s optimistic bias is significantly negatively correlated with the company′s R&D investment, indicating that the analyst′s optimistic bias will inhibit the company′s R&D investment; (2)the higher the institutional investor′s shareholding ratio, the company′s refinancing. The more significant the negative relationship between analyst optimism bias and corporate R&D investment, indicating that the "conflict of interest" will aggravate this relationship; (3)the improvement of corporate information transparency can alleviate the negative effects of analyst optimism bias on corporate R&D investment. This paper further adopts methods such as changing the measurement of analyst attention and analyst optimism bias, selecting a first-order difference model to eliminate possible endogenousness of the model, and defining refinancing behavior only as equity refinancing behavior and changing the measurement of information transparency as robustness tests, and the above robustness tests still support the conclusions of this paper. 
       From a theoretical point of view, this paper enriches and expands the research on the economic consequences of analysts ′optimistic bias and the factors of corporate R&D investment; examines their impact on corporate R&D investment from the perspective of analysts′ optimistic bias, and identifies specific mechanisms and deepen the impact of analysts′ research on corporate innovation activities; and aiming at the negative impact of analysts′ optimistic bias on corporate R&D investment, it further explores the role of "conflicts of interest" faced by analysts and the role of transparency of information. It adds new evidence to the study of analysts′ "conflicts of interest" and corporate information transparency. Some studies have shown that in China′s capital market, the information interpretation mechanism plays a leading role in analysts′ attention to the impact on enterprise innovation. As a whole, analysts′ attention can promote enterprise innovation. The research in this paper finds that analyst optimism bias will have a further effect on corporate innovation. Analyst optimism bias will strengthen the impact of performance pressure mechanism and weaken the effectiveness of the information interpretation mechanism, and generally have a negative impact on corporate R&D investment. This paper expands the research scope of the impact of analysts on corporate innovation. The existing literature usually limits the research object to the number of analysts who track companies. This paper further tests the influence of optimistic bias in analysts′ earnings forecast, and theoretically deepens the understanding of information interpretation mechanism and performance pressure mechanism. Most of the previous studies focused on the influencing factors of analysts′ optimistic bias. In recent years, scholars began to pay attention to its economic consequences. There have been studies on the risk of stock price collapse, enterprise merger and acquisition, etc. In this paper, analysts′ optimistic bias is further related to enterprise R&D investment, thus enriching the research on the economic consequences of analysts′ optimistic bias. In terms of application value, this paper suggests that the supervisory layer needs to further strengthen the isolator system, at the same time strengthen the education of analysts′ professional ethics, improve the professionalism of analysts, ensure the independence and objectivity of analysts, and give full play to analysts as information intermediaries in capital market. In addition, enterprises should further improve the quality of information disclosure and information transparency, so that external investors can correctly judge and evaluate the intrinsic value of the enterprise, strengthen tolerance for innovation failure, and reduce short-term performance pressure on managers. 
        Because this study only focuses on the relationship between analyst optimism bias and R&D investment, it has not yet penetrated into the specific performance of its performance-enhancing pressure mechanism, that is, the mechanism of its action has yet to be further tested. Therefore, follow-up research can be carried out from the perspective of the impact path of analysts′ optimistic bias on corporate R&D investment.
    References | Related Articles | Metrics
    Construction of the performance evaluation indicators of patented technology transfer in universities and its empirical research
    Yang Yang, Liu Wenfei, Ding Kun
    2022, 43(7): 189-199. 
    Abstract ( 189 )  
       Universities, as the supplier of patent technology in the process of patent technology transfer, are responsible for patent knowledge creation and utilization. Enterprises are on the demand side and also the producers of products and services. Chinese government has successively issued a number of policies to coordinate the factors of various parties, promote the construction of bridges between suppliers and demanders, and ensure all participating entities in a sound and reasonable operation during the transfer process. The commercialization of scientific and technological achievements is one of the five construction tasks in the construction of "double first-class" university project. Moreover, technology transfer performance has also been an important index in the evaluation of world-class universities in China. Therefore, the establishment of robust evaluation indicators and the effective evaluation of patent technology transfer is essential to objectively reflect the performance and output of patent technology transfer work in universities, and it is also the basis for the prosper development of university technology transfer.
       In the early research of performance indicator system, researchers mainly focused on the evaluation of the benefits of technology transfer, such as the number of patents licensed or assigned and the actual revenue brought by them. Subsequent research started to concentrate on the potential of technology transfer, such as the number of papers published, the number of patents disclosed, amount of research funding acquired, and the number of personnel equipped, etc. Gradually, evaluation began to cover the whole process of technology transfer as much as possible: from scientific discovery, invention disclosure to patent evaluation; from the creation and management of intellectual property to operation; from individual behavior, group consciousness to organizational management. The cut-in from different angles has enriched the existing evaluation research, but also made the empirical operation more and more difficult, the indicators are difficult to aggregate and lack of systematicness. There are some common limitations in the existing research: First, the sample size of universities is limited. Second, the selection of variables is similar, especially domestic research output indicators are in a simple structure, consisting of the number of technology transfer contracts and the actual income from technology transfer. Third, the research perspective is relatively single and the research ideas are relatively fixed. 
        In view of the above limitations, this paper uses patent data as the new data source to build multi-dimensional performance indicators to enrich and supplement the existing research. It has the following advantages: first, it has a wide data dimension, the transfer of patent rights can be surveyed in the patent transaction information, and the basic patent information contains a variety of information, such as the transferor, inventor, the description of the technology, the recipient, etc., that makes it possible to depict a complete transfer path of patent technology. Secondly, it can be traced back and all statistical indicators can be traced back to a certain patent transfer transaction.
        The research methods of this paper are as follows: (1) Construct a patent basic information table, and extract the patent transfer information from the unstructured transaction data to construct the university patent technology transfer table which concludes the information such as application number, original patentee, transferor, receiver, date of transfer, transferor address, recipient address, transfer type, etc. (2) Join the two tables by primary key patent application number, the entire data includes the inventor, inventor information, patent information, transfer path, recipient and their address which are necessary to support the research in this paper. (3) Based on the above data, construct the performance evaluation index of university patent technology transfer from the four basic elements of knowledge transfer. (4) Comprehensively use evaluation indicators to evaluate technology transfer performance from various levels. The entropy method is used to calculate the corresponding weight of each index, and the Jenks best natural breakpoint method is used to classify the comprehensive value. (5) According to the first level indicators, the top 30 universities are analyzed by hierarchical cluster analysis to indicate the common characteristics of universities in different categories.
       In this study, 17500 pieces of directly-related data are screened out. Based on the theory of knowledge transfer, the performance index system is constructed from four aspects: the transferor, the receiver, the characteristics of technical knowledge and the path of technology transfer, which makes up for the shortcomings of the existing indicators. At the same time, the performance of patent technology transfer of 238 universities in China is evaluated by using the index system. Shanghai Jiaotong University, Tsinghua University, Southeast University are in the first echelon; Harbin University of Technology, Jiangnan University and other universities are in the second echelon; Chongqing University, Wuhan University and other universities are in the third echelon. Nevertheless, the performance forms of different universities can be different within the same echelon. In the empirical process, there are obvious differences in the number of independent transfers, cooperative transfers and internal transfer as well as the length of transfer path among universities. This is related to the internal technology transfer mode of universities, and fully reflects the differences in the management of technology transfer in universities in China. Universities in the north emulate with each other to establish remote institutions in the southeast part of China, aiming to cooperate with local industries in personnel training, innovation and entrepreneurship, achievement commercialization, etc. Meanwhile, universities in the north lack third-party intermediary institutions, besides the intellectual property service industry is not active. Thus, the northern universities mainly rely on the internal asset management department in school. On the contrast, the direct transfer mode in the southeast is dominant, the intellectual property service industry is very active, and the number of third-party service institutions is obviously large. As a whole, among the four levels, there is little difference in terms of technical knowledge characteristics, which is not optimistic, revealing the lack of hierarchical management of intellectual property. Therefore, treating different patents differently and accordingly optimizing the allocation of resources are the next steps for deepening patent technology transfer.
    References | Related Articles | Metrics
    The heterogeneous impact of characteristics of OFDI on the productivity of high-tech enterprises
    Bai Jie
    2022, 43(7): 200-208. 
    Abstract ( 171 )  
       China′s high-tech enterprises are climbing to the high-end link of the global value chain, so they need to improve their innovation ability and total factor productivity in order to enhance their position in the international division of labor system. Due to the rapid change of knowledge, high-tech enterprises rely on their own resources to carry out high-cost innovation activities, which has been difficult to adapt to the increasingly fierce international competition. High tech enterprises can obtain strategic assets such as advanced technology, professional talents, sales channels and management experience through foreign direct investment, improve the position of global value chain, and drive the transformation and upgrading of domestic industries. 
       Based on the existing research, this paper extended the following viewpoints: first, using PSM and did methods to systematically estimate the productivity effect of Chinese high-tech enterprises′ FDI. At present, there is no systematic evaluation of the micro performance of foreign investment of high-tech enterprises. In the past, case analysis, event study and regression analysis were used to study the investment performance of high-tech enterprises. In this paper, by constructing the database of China′s high-tech enterprises′ foreign direct investment in 2008-2015 and adopting the double difference method based on tendency score matching, the grouping effect of FDI enterprises and non-FDI enterprises, the foreign direct investment, and the time effect of the two periods were controlled, and then the net effect of FDI on TFP was studied. The research method effectively controls the endogenous problems caused by sample selection bias and missing variables in the regression process, so as to more accurately identify the causal relationship between FDI and productivity of high-tech enterprises, and ensure the reliability of the research conclusions. Secondly, this paper investigates not only the average effect of OFDI on TFP of high-tech enterprises, but also the dynamic effect of OFDI on TFP of high-tech enterprises. Thirdly, group estimation is made according to investment mode, investment motivation and income level of host country, and the difference of productivity effect of OFDI was investigated from the perspective of investment characteristics. 
        The conclusion shows that: (1) Foreign direct investment has significantly promoted the total factor productivity of high-tech enterprises, and the promotion effect shows a trend of rising first and then declining; (2) Green land investment has a lag effect on the promotion of high-tech enterprises′ TFP, while cross-border M&A has a positive effect on the current and multi-stage TFP. The construction cycle of green space investment is relatively long, and it needs to bear the external integration cost to adapt to the market environment of the host country, which leads to the current productivity effect of green space investment is not significant. With the enterprises gradually embedded in the local production system and knowledge network, the productivity effect of green investment can gradually appear. Through the merger and acquisition of foreign enterprises with specific advantages, Chinese high-tech enterprises can quickly form complementary advantages with the unique knowledge, technology, brand, management experience and other strategic assets of the target enterprises, so as to improve the production efficiency of enterprises and their position in the global value chain; (3) Technology seeking OFDI has the most significant promotion effect on the TFP of high-tech enterprises. The productivity effect of OFDI is lagging behind, but the productivity effect of OFDI is not significant. Technology seeking OFDI is an important way for Chinese high-tech enterprises to adapt to the trend of R&D internationalization and build global R&D system. Enterprises acquire knowledge assets, human capital and cutting-edge technology by establishing R&D institutions, establishing green investment methods such as science and technology parks, as well as mergers and acquisitions of technology leading enterprises. Therefore, this way of acquiring reverse technology spillovers is the most direct and its sustained effect is more obvious; (4) Investment in high-income countries (regions) can significantly improve the production efficiency of enterprises, while investment in low-income countries (regions) cannot significantly improve the production efficiency of enterprises. The investment of enterprises in high-income countries (regions) in emerging market countries can be closer to leading technologies and products, and learn more efficient management mode, so as to improve their own production efficiency.
        The above research provides scientific basis for the rational choice of foreign investment strategy for high-tech enterprises. First, high-tech enterprises need to choose the best market entry strategy in combination with their own strategic orientation. After the financial crisis, more and more high-tech enterprises have invested in the United States, Germany, the United Kingdom and other developed countries to obtain creative assets such as technology and knowledge. However, to obtain reverse technology spillovers, enterprises need to have strong knowledge accumulation, innovation and management capabilities to effectively integrate knowledge assets. Secondly, the government should further improve the overseas investment system and platform construction to provide important support for high-tech enterprises to deeply participate in the international industrial division system. At present, a significant feature of OFDI of high-tech enterprises in China is to move forward to the upstream of the global value chain and gain advanced technology, brand and overseas market management experience through cross-border M&A. We should encourage enterprises to set up research centers or laboratories, international technology transfer institutions and science and technology parks in developed countries such as the United States and the European Union by improving policy support, setting up funds, focusing on cultivation and guidance, and optimizing intermediary services, so as to promote advantageous enterprises to build a global R&D network and enhance the status of the global value chain. Finally, we will improve the multi-level bilateral and multilateral cooperation mechanisms. The investment goal of high-tech enterprises is to obtain high value-added resources such as advanced technology and marketing network, so to achieve the high-end of the value chain. Therefore, they are more likely to face various risks such as technical standard barriers, intellectual property litigation, national security review, etc. Bilateral or multilateral industrial investment cooperation funds can be set up to provide financial support for the development and investment of key industries among countries. In view of some outstanding problems such as weak recognition of China′s technical standards in some countries, we should strengthen the protection of intellectual property rights, coordinate the technical standards with countries along the line, promote the signing of mutual recognition agreements on technical standards, and reduce the risk of enterprises being rejected by the local market due to technical standards.
    References | Related Articles | Metrics